|
STATE
FORMATION IN ANCIENT NORTHEAST AFRICA
AND THE INDIAN OCEAN TRADE
Stanley
M. Burstein
University of California at Los Angeles
The publication in 1974 of
the first volume of Immanuel Wallersteins The Modern WorldËSystem1
was a milestone in the historiography of world history. For
the first time the whole complex history of the world since
the sixteenth century CE had been presented as part of single
integrated process in which social and political structures
were correlated with regional economic roles. Wallersteins
by now familiar classification of world regions into core,
semi-periphery, and periphery provided an elegant framework
for analyzing the socio-economic history of the various regions
in terms of their function in the World System. Wallersteins
scheme has been criticized on many grounds including putative
Eurocentrism and overemphasis on the significance of economic
factors in history.2
Probably, no aspect of his work has drawn more criticism,
however, than his insistence that the world system was uniquely
characteristic of modern history because its appearance was
dependent on the emergence of modern capitalism.
Wallerstein did not deny the
existence of interregional trade prior to the sixteenth century
CE, but he insisted that it was primarily a small-scale trade
in luxuries that operated within an essentially political
framework provided by what he called world empires. Wallersteins
denial of the applicability of World System analysis to antiquity
and the middle ages has seemed unconvincing to many scholars,
and there have been numerous attempts to identify earlier
World Systems. The most far-reaching of such attempts has
been that of Andre Gunder Frank,3
who has argued in numerous works that the current World System
did not originate in the sixteenth century CE but actually
has existed for over five thousand years, beginning with the
economic integration of Egypt and Mesopotamia in the early
fourth millennium BCE, and expanding outward continuously
from that original core until it reached its present world-wide
extent.
Gunder Franks expansive reconstruction
of the history of the Modern World System has found few followers.
More common have been attempts—primarily by archaeologists‹to
identify smaller and more localized pre-modern øWorld SystemsÓ
in which various regions formed functionally integrated trading
systems organized around a regional economic core.4
All such attempts to extend strict World System analysis into
pre-modern times, whether general such as that of Gunder Frank
or more limited archaeologically defined World Systems, have
foundered, however, on their inability to demonstrate that
ancient or medieval states were able to project sufficient
power‹political, military, or economic‹to reconfigure neighboring
regions as semi-peripheries and peripheries as required by
conventional World System theory.
Janet Abu-Lughod in Before European Hegemony proposed a less ambitious
but potentially more widely applicable model. According to
Abu-Lughod, a Medieval World System that was made possible
by the Mongol Conquests of the thirteenth century CE preceded
Wallersteins modern world system. Unlike the Modern World
System, however, the Medieval World System was not functionally
integrated around a central core, but segmentary, consisting
of a series of regionally defined trading subsystems—each
with its own core and periphery—that interlocked to create
a single world trading system extending from Europe to China.
In this system the Indian Ocean and its two great gulfs‹the
Red Sea and the Persian‹formed a key link, connecting the
Mediterranean basin, Near East, and East Africa to the Indian
subcontinent, itself the bridge between the Indian Ocean circuit
and Southeast Asia and China.5
THE ANCIENT INDIAN OCEAN TRADE
Although Abu-Lughod confined
her analysis to the high Middle Ages, the economic pattern
described by her was not unique. Similar economic configurations
also can be identified in antiquity. Specifically, an almost
identically structured ancient world trading system in which
the Indian Ocean also served as a key link between east and
west emerged in the first century BCE and lasted until the
third century CE. Study of the Ancient World System as a whole
has hardly begun. Synthetic works are few,6 while most scholarship
has been philological in character, concentrating on identifying
the places and products mentioned in the sources, relating
written and archaeological evidence, and establishing a reliable
chronology for the various phases of the Ancient World System
in general and the Indian Ocean trade in particular. Moreover,
as is true in the case of the Medieval World System, the primary
focus of scholarship concerning the Indian Ocean trading system
in antiquity has been its connection with historical developments
in the Indian subcontinent.7 The purpose of this paper is modest: to outline the
principal changes in the Indian Ocean trading system in the
late first century BCE and the mid-first century CE and to
examine the impact of those changes on the two principal states
in ancient Northeast Africa, Kush and Axum.
The difficulties in such an
undertaking are formidable. The predominantly philological
character of ancient Indian Ocean studies is a reflex of the
inadequacies of the extant sources when compared with what
is available to historians dealing with the Modern World System
or even the Medieval World System. Although written sources
exist in a wide variety of languages including Greek, Latin,
Sanskrit, Geez, ancient south Arabic, Tamil, Sanskrit, and
even Chinese, these sources are limited in quantity and quality.
The vast majority are brief references or allusions without
clear chronological or socio-economic context that occur in
a wide variety of literary and technical works dealing with
other subjects. Only one short work‹the so-called Periplus
of the Erythraean Sea written by an unknown but clearly
knowledgeable author‹describes the Indian Ocean trading system
as whole, and it has required over a century of scholarship
just to convincingly demonstrate that this text is to be dated
to the mid-first century CE.8
Also lacking are detailed business records and correspondence
that would permit studies of changes over time in the mechanics,
content, and volume of the trade, although the recent publication
of a papyrus discovered in Egypt detailing a consignment of
goods from India in the early second century CE raises the
hope of the discovery of further examples of this type of
evidence.9 These deficiencies in the written sources are only partially
offset by the steadily growing body of archaeological evidence,
which allows us to track the origin and distribution of goods
but not how they reached their various destinations or why.10
As a result, studies of the Indian Ocean trade and its historical
significance are inevitably schematic with numerous gaps in
our knowledge and understanding and greater clarity concerning
the general outlines of the trades history and structure
than its details, and that is no less true of this paper.
As already mentioned, thanks
to the fortunate survival of the Periplus
of the Erythraean Sea we have a comprehensive overview
of the Indian Ocean trading system at one critical point in
its history, namely, in the mid-first century CE, when the
effects of the wide spread use of the southeast monsoon by
ships bound for India were making themselves generally felt
for the first time. Archaeological evidence and cuneiform
sources, however, indicate that the origins of the Indian
Ocean trading system lay much further back in history. References
to the presence of Indian language interpreters and resident
Indians in southern Mesopotamia suggest that a well organized
coastal trade between the Indus Valley civilization and Mesopotamia
via the coasts of the Indian Ocean and Persian Gulf already
existed in the mid-third millennium BCE.11
While the collapse of the
Indus Valley civilization in the mid-second millennium BCE
temporarily interrupted this trade, the connection was not
only reestablished in the early first millennium BCE but extended
westward to include already existing trading systems in southern
Arabia and the Red Sea basin, thereby making it possible for
the first time for Indian goods to reach Egypt and the eastern
Mediterranean basin entirely by sea as well as by the millennia
old river and caravan routes running through Mesopotamia and
Syria.12 Explicit evidence
for the scale and contents of the early Indian Ocean trade
is lacking. The emphasis on the rarity of Indian goods in
the extant sources suggests, however, that it was still relatively
small in scale. References to the presence in western
Asia of various Indian agricultural products including rice
and humped cattle, domesticated chickens and peafowl, as well
as to Indian textiles, and the existence of loan words in
Greek and other Mediterranean languages for Indian spices
such as pepper and ginger indicate that many of the products
typical of the fully developed late Hellenistic and early
Roman period trade were already being traded westward.13
Although the geographical
framework of the Indian Ocean trading system established in
the early and middle first millennium BCE remained essentially
unchanged for the rest of antiquity, the Periplus of the Erythraean Sea and other sources
including Pliny the Elders Natural
History and Ptolemys Geography
reveal major changes in its scale, organization, and conduct
during the late Hellenistic and early Roman imperial periods.
Those changes were three fold. First, direct sea contact between
India and the Mediterranean became more common as a result
of the increasing use of the southeast monsoon by merchantmen
based in Roman Egypt. Second, the explosion in Roman demand
for south Indian products including textiles, pearls and especially
pepper, which rapidly became a staple of Mediterranean cuisine,14 increased the scale
and value of the trade to a level clearly beyond that of a
limited trade in øluxuries,Ó particularly with the use of
large ships, each one of which could carry more than a hundred
times the bulk of the consignment of three and a half tons
of ivory, textiles and spices detailed on the papyrus document
mentioned above.15 Third and finally, Roman demand for
south Indian goods meant that the focus of the trade shifted
during the first century CE from its traditional center in
northwest India to southwest Indian ports such as Muziris,
modern Cranganore in southern Malabar.
The organization and
development of the direct sea trade to India is outlined in
an important passage of the Natural
History of the first century CE encyclopedist Pliny the
Elder,16
which makes it clear that the underlying reason for the radical
transformation of the Indian Ocean trade at this time was
the desire by Roman merchants to increase profits by gaining
direct access to the sources of the desired products. As was
true in the Middle Ages, the ancient Indian Ocean trading
system traditionally had consisted of a series of interlocking
regional trading networks, so that the same person rarely
traversed the whole system. Goods bound for the west or east,
instead, passed through the hands of numerous intermediaries
with attendant rises in cost as they changed hands at each
stage. There was, therefore, a strong incentive for peoples
at either extreme of the system to reduce costs and increase
profits by eliminating the various intermediate stages and
the ømiddlemenÓ who dominated them.
The initiative in establishing
direct contact between the Mediterranean and India appears
to have come from the Indian side in the late second century
BCE. The Ptolemaic rulers of Egypt responded in
kind, dispatching at least two official trading missions to
India while establishing a Greek presence on the island of
Socotra just outside the southern entrance to the Red Sea
alongside the already existing Indian and Arabian settlements
on the island and charging a special official with general
oversight over commerce in the Red Sea and the Indian Ocean.17 The Ptolemies
Roman successors continued these initiatives with such dramatic
results that by the beginning of the Common Era the Greek
geographer Strabo could observe that øin earlier times not
twenty vessels dared to traverse the Red Sea so as to emerge
beyond the straits; but now great fleets are sent as far as
India€whence the most valuable cargoes are brought back to
Egypt and thence exported again to other places.Ó18
The ramifications of these
developments for countries involved in the Indian Ocean trade
were far-reaching. One result was the establishment
of relatively regular diplomatic relations between Rome and
India with the first Indian embassy to Rome being attested
as early as 20 BCE, barely a decade after the Roman conquest
of Egypt.19 Unfortunately, the
sources are silent about the purposes of these embassies,
but the Periplus of the Erythraean
Sea suggests that facilitating trade between Roman Egypt
and India may have been among them since it reveals the existence
in the first century CE of a sophisticated commercial infrastructure
intended to accommodate such trade including a system of designated
ports of trade together with harbor pilots, legal and military
protection for foreign traders,20
and the presence of a small western trade diaspora in a number
of Indian ports. Contemporary archaeological and textual evidence
documents the substantial impact made by the increased availability
of Indian on Roman imperial material culture.21
Equally important, the
sources also clearly indicate that there was a close correlation
between state formation and political relations between states
in western and especially southern India and shifts in the
focus of the Indian Ocean trade, encouraging, according to
Kenneth Hall:22
€the development of south
Indian ports as independent commercial centers, free from
the earlier dependency upon ports on the northwestern coast€.Former
tribal chiefs are seen seizing the opportunity offered by
the expanding trade to organize the flow of trade goods out
of the hinterland and into the coastal ports, expanding their
political hegemony in the process€.Corresponding to this political
development, and responding to the demand for local commodities
by the Roman traders‹pepper and cloth goods especially‹new
hinterland commercial and political centers evolved. It is
no coincidence that the most illustrious hinterland urban
center of that time, the Pandya capital of Madurai, was strategically
located at the center of a major cotton producing and weaving
region and was as well directly linked to the major trans-peninsular
caravan route between the western and eastern coasts (sc.
of southern India).
The focus of scholarship on the eastern segments of the Indian
Ocean trade is understandable since, as was true of the Medieval
World System, India was the primary goal of the trade and
the sources, not surprisingly, are fullest for that aspect
of it. It has had, however, the unfortunate effect of
obscuring the fact that expansion of the Indian Ocean trade
also had similarly important impacts on the development of
states at the other end of the system in northeast Africa.23
ANCIENT NORTHEAST AFRICA AND THE INDIAN OCEAN TRADE
Like its eastern counterpart,
the western segment of the Indian Ocean trading system was
already millennia old and complex in structure, when the Periplus
of the Erythraean Sea reveals it as it functioned in the
mid-first century CE. Also like its eastern counterpart, the
western segment of the Indian Ocean trading system was not
a single unified system but was itself composed of three relatively
independent regional trading networks: a southern network
comprising approximately the area of present day Somalia and
the coast of East Africa at least as far south as Zanzibar
that was dominated by the kingdom of Himyar in ancient southern
Arabia; another dominated by the kingdom of Axum located in
the highlands of modern Eritrea and focused on the southwestern
coasts of the Red Sea, a region that was known in antiquity
as the Incense Bearing Country; and, and, finally, an inland
system centered on the Nile that was dominated by the Kingdom
of Kush in the Central Sudan. What was common to all
three of these networks was their function as a periphery
supplying primarily African products‹gold, ivory, incense,
hard woods such as ebony, exotic animals and animal skins,
and, of course, slaves‹to an economic core formed by Egypt
and its neighbors in the eastern Mediterranean basin.
While all three components
of the western segment of the Indian Ocean trading system
were exposed to the stresses resulting from the rapid transformation
of the Indian Ocean trade in the late first century BCE and
the first century CE, it was the Nile valley portion of the
system, which was the oldest and for most of its history the
most important of them, that proved to be most vulnerable
to those stresses. The Nile Valley has been described for
good reason as a øCorridor to Africa.Ó24
It forms an over a thousand mile long narrow oasis running
through the great desert that extends across the whole of
North Africa from the Atlantic Ocean to the Red Sea, thereby
providing the most convenient route by which various sub-Saharan
African products could be transported to Egypt whence they
could be distributed throughout the Mediterranean basin.
Throughout antiquity and beyond the rulers of Egypt dreamed
of gaining direct access to these sources by securing control
of the whole of the Nile corridor.
The formidable glacis of lower
Nubia with its harsh deserts and numerous stretches of rapids,
the so-called cataracts of the Nile, however, hindered achievement
of that goal. These obstacles were not, of course, insurmountable.
The kings of the New Kingdom in the second millennium BCE
and the Twenty-Fifth Dynasty in the First Millennium BCE demonstrated
that they could be overcome with sufficient effort, but most
Egyptian dynasties were unwilling to expend the required effort
and resources, preferring instead to achieve their goals by
less costly means. They maintained strong defensive positions
in Lower Nubia and freely used military force to intimidate
or even subdue potentially hostile states further south in
Nubia, while relying on diplomacy and trade to assure the
steady flow of African products north to Egypt. Geography,
therefore, created the opportunity for the emergence in the
second and first millenniums BCE of a series of states between
the third and sixth cataracts of the Nile‹the region the Egyptians
referred to as Kush‹that prospered by organizing the collection
and transport to Egypt of African products.25
Despite superficial differences
in the details of their organization, these states shared
certain common characteristics. Specifically, they all were
quasi-confederate in structure, consisting of a union of local
chiefdoms united by their allegiance to a paramount chief
or king, who was believed to be the divinely appointed ruler
and protector of Kush. Ideology was reinforced by the kings
ability to attract the loyalty of followers by various means
including the Egyptianization of elite culture and especially
the kings control of øprestige-goods exchange, the
wealth of which materialized a ruling ideology and acted as
a political currency to finance the leadership.Ó26
In the case of Kush that meant goods imported from Egypt,
which Kushite kings used to enhance the unique status of themselves
and their supporters through redistribution, a process that
is reflected archaeologically in the fact that such imported
prestige-goods are found only in Kushite royal and elite residential
and burial sites.
It was the significance of
such prestige-goods in the political economy of Kush that
determined how trade was conducted in the Nile corridor. Although
a limited non-official trade in African goods existed, the
role of private merchants was limited. Instead, trade between
Kush and Egypt was organized primarily as a royal monopoly
in which Kushite kings provided goods directly to their Egyptian
counterparts or their representatives. The system is known
primarily from Egyptian sources, which refer to the goods
involved as inw, øofficial
giftsÓ, in the Pharaonic period and dora, øgiftsÓ, or xenia, øfriendship giftsÓ,
in the Hellenistic Period and interpret their arrival in Egypt
as recognition by Kush of Egyptian suzerainty in return for
which they were rewarded with what Egyptian texts call
øthe breath of lifeÓ.27
Archaeological evidence from Kush and textual evidence from
the Near East, where the system also functioned, leave no
doubt that the Kushites received not only the øbreath of lifeÓ
but also substantial counter-gifts which provided them with
the prestige goods they redistributed to their supporters.
As Timothy Earle has pointed out, however, societies that
rely on such øinternational prestige-gift exchangeÓ
are øvulnerable to forces beyond the influence of local action,Ó29
and Kush was no exception. Unlike the situation in India,
those forces did not involve changes in the source of goods—the
various goods involved in the western trade network were readily
available throughout northeast Africa‹but in the emergence
of the Red Sea as the primary trade route in the region as
a result of the great expansion of direct sea-borne commerce
between Roman Egypt and India in the late first century BCE
and the first century CE.
Egyptian attempts to acquire
an alternate source of African and south Arabian goods by
establishing contact via the Red Sea with the region they
called øPuntÓ, essentially the coastal regions of the
Sudan and Eritrea,30
are attested as early as the third millennium BCE, but the
costs and difficulties of maintaining a naval presence on
the Red Sea combined with the convenience of the Nile corridor
limited the frequency and extent of such trade, which remained
largely confined to episodic incidents of øprestige-giftÓ
exchange, until the Hellenistic period, when the construction
of a canal linking the Nile and to the Red Sea31
and the creation of a series of an Elephant hunting stations
on the Egyptian and Sudanese coasts of the Red fostered the
development of a small private trade with these regions along
side the long established official øprestige-giftÓ exchange
system.32
The late Hellenistic and early Roman period expansion of the
Indian Ocean trade rapidly transformed this almost three millennia
old system by greatly increasing the number and size of private
ships traversing the Red Sea and using its ports, where African
goods could be acquired for shipment either north to Roman
Egypt or south and east to ports further along in the broader
Indian Ocean trading system.32a Geography dictated
that it would not be the largely landlocked kingdom of
Kush but that of Axum in the highlands of modern Ethiopia
that benefited from these changes.
Evidence for early history of the kingdom of Axum is scant,
but it indicates that, unlike Kush, Axum was of relatively
recent origin.33
Although archaeological evidence suggests that its roots lie
in the early first millennium BCE, when South Arabian colonists
founded a series of small kingdoms in the territory of modern
Eritrea and Tigray in Ethiopia, the kingdom of Axum began
its rise to prominence only in the late Hellenistic period,
when the ruler of one of these kingdoms, that of the
Habasha (=Abyssinians), astutely chose the site of the future
city of Axum as his capital. Located on the Ethiopian plateau
with ready access to the upper Nile Valley and its hinterlands
on the west and to the Red Sea on the east through the port
of Adulis near modern Massawa, Axum was ideally situated to
profit from the new conditions in the Red Sea created by the
expansion of the Indian Ocean trade, and the kings of Axum
took advantage of this opportunity, creating as was being
done in contemporary India, the essential infrastructure to
accommodate the increase in shipping by establishing in agreement
with Rome Adulis as a designated port of trade and encouraging
the development of a trade diaspora in their kingdom.34
As a result of these developments,
Adulis had become by the mid-first century CE the principal
center for the export of goods from the coastal regions of
the Red Sea and its hinterlands. Indeed, the Periplus
of the Erythraean Sea reveals that by that time ivory
collected in Sennar in Kushite territory was being exported
through Adulis instead of being brought to Meroe for transportation
to Egypt through the Nile corridor.35
Their second and third century CE successors continued these
policies, extending their rule over most of the hinterlands
of the southern Red Sea basin and building and maintaining
a caravan route to Egypt that bypassed the Nile corridor entirely,36
thereby confirming Axums rule as the principal supplier of
African goods to Roman Egypt in particular and the Mediterranean
basin in general and winning recognition as one of the four
great kingdoms in the world known to the peoples of the Near
East and Mediterranean basin.37
It took time for the effects
of these developments on Kush to become evident. Indeed, the
late first century BCE and the first half of the first century
CE was in many ways the climax of Kushite history. Peaceful
relations between Rome and Kush resulted in unprecedented
prosperity. The evidence is primarily archaeological and includes:
widespread building and repair of temples, palaces, and other
elite structures, expansion of agricultural settlement and
installations, and, of course, numerous objects imported
from Roman Egypt that have been discovered on Meroitic sites.38
Contained in this latter substantial but little studied body
of evidence is a wide variety of small but high quality metal,
glass, and ceramic objects including eating utensils; items
related to personal adornment such as rings, jewelry, beads,
and mirrors; and household furnishings and decorative objects.
In addition, the existence of classical motifs and images
in Roman period Meroitic art and architecture, Greek auloi
and statues of aulos and
lyre players,39
and a column drum inscribed with the Greek alphabet may imply
the presence also in Kush either of individuals skilled in
their production and use or appropriate models. Kush even
played a minor role in the Indian Ocean trade through a narrow
corridor leading from the vicinity of the fourth cataract
of the Nile to the coast of the Red Sea near modern Suakin.40
By the end of second
century and early third CE, however, conditions had changed
dramatically. The emergence of Axum as Romes primary source
of African goods gradually reduced diplomatic contact between
Kush and Roman Egypt as Roman policy toward the Upper Nile
valley increasingly focused on the defense of the southern
frontier of Egypt. Consequently, relations with the peoples
of Lower Nubia took precedence of those with Kush, thereby
drying up the prestige goods trade on which the Kushites
monarchys wealth was based. Again the evidence is primarily
archaeological. At Meroe, the Kushite capital, significant
new temple construction virtually ceased, the size of royal
pyramids shrank to a fraction of that of their first century
CE predecessors, and, most importantly, evidence for imported
Roman luxury goods in royal burials almost totally disappears.
Increasing impoverishment of the Kushite central government
was paralleled by the appearance for the first time of rich
elite residences and cemeteries in or near important regional
administrative centers in Lower Nubia together with epigraphical
evidence pointing to the transformation of important administrative
and military offices in the region into hereditary fiefdoms,41
thereby, weakening the Kushite monarchys control over its
peripheral territories and exposing it to attack and
ultimately conquest by neighboring peoples and states such
as the Noba and Blemmyes and especially Axum. As usual, the
sources to trace the process in detail are lacking.
When the evidence allows us again to observe conditions in
the region in Late Antiquity, however, the kingdom of Kush
has disappeared, being replaced by a series of warring successor
states, and the Nile corridor has ceased to be a significant
artery for the transmission of African goods to Egypt; while
Axum has become Romes principal ally in Africa and the main
intermediary between India and the Mediterranean basin in
a reorganized and smaller but still vigorous Indian Ocean
trade.
CONCLUSION
This paper is only a
preliminary sketch of a long and complex historical process.
Much of importance has had to be omitted, partly for lack
of space such as the impact of changes in the political economy
of Roman Egypt on trade relations with Kush and Axum or the
role of trade diasporas in the spread of Christianity and,
later, Islam in the Red Sea basin; and partly for lack of
evidence such as the impact of the Indian Ocean trade on cultures
located on the east coast of Africa.42
Hopefully, however, it has also demonstrated the error of
treating of developments in ancient northeast Africa in isolation
from the rest of the history of events in the Indian Ocean
region as a whole.
Notes
1 Immanuel Wallerstein, The
Modern-World System, 3 vols. (New York 1974-1989).
2 For a convenient summary of criticism of World System
theory see Thomas Richard Shannon, An
Introduction to the World-System Perspective (Boulder,
1989), 137-169.
3 Gunder Frank has argued his position in numerous works.
A good introduction is Andre Gunder Frank and Barry K. Gills,
øThe Five Thousand Year World System: An Interdisciplinary
Introduction,Ó Humboldt Journal
of Social Relations, 18 (1992): 1-79.
4 E.g. Michael Rowlands, Mogens Larsen and Kristian
Kristiansen, editors, Centre and Periphery in the Ancient World (Cambridge, 1987); and Greg
Woolf, øWorld-systems analysis and the Roman empire,Ó Journal of Roman Archaeology, 3 (1990): 44-58. For a critique of such
archaeological øWorld SystemsÓ see Gil J. Stein, Rethinking World-Systems: Disaporas, Colonies, and Interaction in Uruk
Mesopotamia (Tucson, 1999).
5 Abu Lughod, Before European Hegemony: The World System ¥A.D.
1250-135 (New York, 1989), 261-290.
6 The only comprehensive survey of the evidence for
Roman trade beyond the borders of the empire, now sadly outdated,
is Mortimer Wheeler, Rome
Beyond the Imperial Frontiers (London, 1954).
7 The standard treatment of the ancient Indian Ocean
trade is E. H. Warmington, The Commerce between the Roman Empire and India,
2nd. Edition (London, 1974). Warmingtons account has been
updated M. G. Raschke, øNew Studies in Roman Commerce with
the EastÓ in Aufstieg und Niedergang der Romischen Welt, II.9.2
(Berlin, 1978): 604-1378; and Federico DE Romanis, Cassia, Cinnamomo, Ossidiana: Uomo e Merci tra Oceano Indiano e Mediterraneo
(Rome, 1996.
8 The currently accepted date is ca. 40 to 70 CE; cf.
W. Raunig, øDie Versuchung einer Datierung des Periplus
maris Erythraei,Ó Mitteilungen
der anthropologischen Gesellschaft in Wien, 100 (1970):
231-242 for a review of the scholarship. The standard
edition is Lionel Casson, The Periplus Maris Erythraei (Princeton,
1989).
9 Lionel Cssson, øNew Light on Maritime Loans: P. Vind.
G 40822,Ó Zeitschrift fur Papyrologie und Epigraphik, 84 (1990): 195-206.
10 For the archaeological evidence see Vimala Begley
and Richard Daniel de Pubma, editors, Rome
and India: The Ancient Sea Trade (Madison, 1991).; and
Rosa Maria Cimino, editor, Ancient
Rome and India: Commercial and cultural contacts between the
Roman world and India (New Delhi, 1994).
11 A. L. Oppenheim, øThe Seafaring Merchants of Ur,Ó
JAOS, 74 (1954): 6-17;
Klaus Karttunen, India in
Early Greek Literature (Helsinki, 1989), 11-15.
12 Karttunen, India,
19-31.
13 Karttunen, India,
26-27.
14 Cf. J. Innes Miller, The
Spice Trade of the Roman Empire: 29 B.C. to A.D. 641 (Oxford,
1969), 80-83. The transformation of pepper from a luxury to
a staple is indicated by the decline in its price in the west
during antiquity; cf. Stanislaw Mrozek, øZum Handel von einigen
Gewurzen und Wohlgeruchen in der spatromischen Zeit,Ó Munstersche Beitrage zur antiken Handelsgeschichte, 1,2 (1982): 15-21.
16 Pliny, Natural History 6.101-106.
17 That Indians were exploring westward toward the
Red Sea is clear from Strabos (Geography 2.3.4, p. 98) account of the background
to the first Ptolemaic voyages to India. For the official
character of the Ptolemaic voyages see J. H. Thiel, Eudoxus
of Cyzicus: A Chapter in the History of the Sea-Route to India
and the Route Round the Cape in Ancient Times (Groningen,
1966), 18-22. For settlement of Socotra see Hermann
Bengtson, øKosmas Indikopleustes und die Ptolemaier,Ó Historia, 4 (1955): 151-156.
18 Strabo, Geography 17.1.18, p. 798.
19 M. P. Charlesworth, øRoman Trade with India: A ResurveyÓ
in Studies in Roman Economic
and Social History in Honor of Allan Chester Johnson,
edited by P. R. Coleman-Norton et al. (Princeton, 1951), 140-141;
Warmington, Commerce,
35-37; and Raschke, øNew Studies,Ó
1045 n. 1623.
20 Ports: Casson, Periplus,
27. Protection: Lionel Casson, ø Sakas versus Andhras in the
Periplus Maris ErythraeiÓ
in Lionel Casson, Ancient
Trade and Society (Detroit, 1984), 216-218. Disaspora:
Romila Thapar, øEarly Mediterranean Contacts with India: An
OverviewÓ in Crossings: Early
Mediterranean Contacts with India, edited by F. De Romanis
and A. Tchernia (New Delhi, 1997), 34-38; Casson, øNew Light,Ó
206.
21 The evidence for Indian influence on Roman Imperial
material culture is collected in Federico De Romanis, øRome
and the Notia of India:
Relations between Rome and Southern India from 30 BC to the
Flavian PeriodÓ in Crossings, 80-160.
22 Kenneth Hall, øThe Expansion of Roman Trade in the
Indian Ocean: An Indian Perspective,Ó The
Elmira Review, (1979): 42; cf. Thapar, øEarly Mediterranean
Contacts,Ó 30.
23 Cf. the comments of R. J. Barendse on the similar
lack of attention to East Africa in discussions of the Medieval
and Modern World Systems; R. J. Barendse, øTrade and State
in the Arabian Seas: A Survey from the Fifteenth to the Eighteenth
Century, Journal of World
History, 11 (2000): 178-180.
24 The concept of the øNile corridorÓ was developed
by William Y. Adams in William Y. Adams, Nubia:
Corridor to Africa (Princeton, 1977), 13-43.
25 For the history and archaeology of Kush see Adams,
Nubia: and Laszlo Torok,
The Kingdom of Kush: Handbook
of the Napatan-Meroitic Civilization (Leiden, 1997).
26 Timothy Earle, How
Chiefs Come to Powre: The Political Economy in Prehistory
(Stanford, 1997), 209.
27 Edward Bleiberg, The
Official Gift in Ancient Egypt (Norman, 1996); Adam Lajtar,
øDie konteakte zwischen Agypten und dem Horn von Afrika im
2. Jh. v. Chr.,Ó The Journal of Juristic Papyrology, 29 (1999):
51-66.
29 Timothy Earle, How
Chiefs Come to Power, 210.
30 Cf. K. A. Kitchen, øPunt and How to Get There,Ó
Orientalia, Ser. 2, 40
(1971): 184-207; Jacke Phillips, øPunt and Aksum: Egypt and
the Horn of Africa,Ó Journal
of African History, 38 (1997): 423-457. The archaeological
evidence for the Red Sea in antiquity is summarized in Rodolfo
Fattovich, øLarchaeologia nel Mar Rosso: problemi e prospettive.
Note in margine all recente pubblicazione di due siti costieri
dell Somalia settentrionale,Ó Annali,
55 (1995): 158-176.
31 Carol A. Redmount, øThe Wadi Tumilat and the ¥Canal
of the Pharaohs,Ó JNES, 54 (1995): 127-135.
32 Cf. Ulrich Wilcken, øPunt-Fahrten in der Ptolemaerzeit,Ó
ZAS, 60 (1925): 86-102;
S. M. Burstein, øIvory and Ptolemaic Exploration of the Red
Sea: The Missing Factor,Ó Topoi,
6 (1996): 799-807.
32a For evidence pointing to the development of trade
between the peoples of the southern Red Sea and India see
Lionel Casson, øEgypt, Africa, Arabia, and India: Patterns
of Seaborne Trade in the First Century A.D.,Ó The
Bulletin of the American Society of Papyrologists, 31
(1984): 39-47.
33 For the history and archaeology of Axum see Stuart
Munro-Hay, Aksum: An African Civilization of Late Antiquity (Edinburgh, 1991);
and David W. Phillipson, Ancient
Ethiopia: Aksum: Its Antecedents and Successors (London,
1998).
34 Adulis: Stuart Munro-Hay, øThe Foreign Trade of
the Aksumite Port of Adulis,Ó Azania, 17 (1982): 107-125. Diaspora: Periplus of the Erythraean Sea 6; Stanley Burstein,
editor, Ancient African Civilizations:
Kuth and Axum (Princeton, 1998), 94-96.
35 Periplus of the Erythraean Sea 4.
36 Burstein, Ancient African Civilizations, 85, 89-90.
37 Dierter Metzler, øUber das Konzept der ¥Vier grossen
Konigreiche in Manis Kephalaia (cap. 77),Ó Klio, 71 (1989): 447.
38 The fullest list is contained in Löszlã Tðrðk, "Kush
and the external world," Meroitica, 10 (1989)
: 117-150. For a more select list intended to highlight
the chronological implications of classical imports, see Inge
Hofmann, BeitrØge zur meriotischen Chronologie ( Vienna,
1978), 198-30.
40 Pliny, Natural History 6.189.
41 Torok, Kingdom of Kush, 497-499.
42 For the first archaeological evidence of Roman trade
with the East African coast see Felix A. Chami, øRoman Beads
from the Rufiji Delta, Tanzania: First Incontrovertable Archaeological
Link with the Periplus,Ó Current
Anthropology, 40 (1999): 237-241.
|
Copyright Statement
Copyright: © 2001 by the American Historical
Association. Compiled by Debbie Ann Doyle. Format by Chris Hale.
|