D-Lib Magazine | |
Thomas Moritz |
(This Opinion piece presents the opinions of the author. It does not necessarily reflect the views of D-Lib Magazine, its publisher, the Corporation for National Research Initiatives, or its sponsor.) Provision of free, universal access to biodiversity information is a practical imperative for the international conservation community this goal should be accomplished by promotion of the Public Domain and by development of a sustainable Biodiversity Information Commons adapting emergent legal and technical mechanisms to provide a free, secure and persistent environment for access to and use of biodiversity information and data. ProblemsBiodiversity Information. A very extensive body of data and information has been accumulated concerning the world's biological diversity. These resources reside in universities, libraries, museums, government agencies, research institutions and conservation organizations as well as in the traditional knowledge of indigenous peoples. They are typically not coherently organized nor integrated so it is difficult for researchers to quickly and effectively find the data and information they need. Major investments continue to be made to expand this raw knowledge base. To date because these data and information are generally not coherently managed, even key stakeholders have only fragmentary, incomplete access to them. Beyond the limitations imposed by inadequate management, the "ownership" or "intellectual property rights" (IPR) vested in these resources creates barriers to access for many stakeholders in the world biodiversity conservation community. When limitations of proprietary control are amplified by market-based charges for acquisition or use of data or information, barriers may be insurmountable. Compounding this problem is the conspicuous global disproportion in distribution of wealth and the huge continuing investment in unsustainable development met with inadequate levels of investment in conservation. Thus, while weak management of information impedes the fully informed participation of many stakeholders in biodiversity conservation, marketbased cost barriers exclude entire sectors of the global community. The Information Gradient/Digital Divide. There has long been an "information gradient" that runs North to South and prevents most peoples in the South (as well as many in the North) from equitable, direct access to biodiversity information. This gradient is both digital and analog. (As an instance of the "analog" portion of this gradient, in Pakistan, prior to partition with India there was a single university; in the subsequent 50 years 32 universities and more than 100 colleges, training institutes and other specialized institutions of higher education have been founded 1. A review of simple collections measures such as serial holdings in these university libraries reveals the extremity of the North-South disparity in distribution of information resources.) Moreover, the ascendancy of the Internet, in particular with regard to the use of the Web, adds a layer of technological complexity and cost to an international information regime that is already severely inequitable. The gradient most adversely affects the communities most likely to engage in constructive conservation the public sector, the applied conservation community (NGOs, etc.), the academic/education community and the research sectors. (These are, of course, overlapping sectors.) The "Second Enclosure" Movement.2 The past decade has seen the emergence of a "second enclosure" movement as information has increasingly been treated as a commodity subject to new proprietary restrictions. Even organizations that do not seek direct profit from information (e.g., many conservation organizations) are hesitant to make their data and information freely available for fear that they will be taken advantage of (i.e., be seen somehow to have incompetently "given away the store"). In this commercial information environment, market mechanisms and the assertion of "intellectual property rights" are incompatible with free, equitable and universal access to essential information and data for all members of the international community. The difficulties originally posed by proprietary restrictions on production of AIDS drugs are but one example of how the prevalent regime of intellectual property rights and laws can fail to serve the common good. As has happened in the case of AIDS drugs, international civil society must come to broad consensus concerning the classes of data and information whose necessity to the public good transcends the utility of market control or the requirements of corporate self-interest3. Solution: Biodiversity Commons4Public Domain. In Anglo-American law the notion of the "public domain" recognizes that there is broad social value to placing information in a public commons for free, general use by all (including commercial uses). Much conservation information and data can simply be placed in the public domain, and the international conservation community should support and encourage such placement. Instances of this class of information might include taxonomic names of organisms and a basic world database of protected areas. However, there are many instances of information that are not in the public domain that present more complex rights management dilemmas. For example, some images owned by professional photographers might be made available for not-for-profit conservation uses particularly as low-resolution derivatives but also could be licensed or sold as higher resolution digital objects for commercial use. Complexly composed data or information objects (involving information or data licensed from multiple sources) may similarly be inappropriate or unavailable for unconditional placement in the public domain. Information Commons. An "information commons" defines a community of use and guarantees free unhindered access to data and information for that community within a defined information space. Such a commons is composed of public domain data and information as well as otherwise protected information that is made openly available and that limits the full exercise of intellectual property rights by rights holders. Producers of information may assign rights to such a commons (just as owners of real estate may grant development "easements" on their property to a conservancy) while maintaining traditional controls over their intellectual property rights in the larger international commercial market domain. This is sometimes described as a "conditional" (or even "impure") domain of use. Cost FactorsDigital Information as a Public Good and as an Extensible Resource. A unique property of information particularly in digital form is that it is not a finite resource in the sense that copies or additional increments of use of information and data, once created, have virtually zero transaction costs. Hence, the "tragedy of the commons"5 syndrome does not apply. In economic terms, these digital resources are "nonrivalrous". This distinctive quality of digital information enables the provision of open access on the Internet at virtually no additional cost for each incremental user. True Costs of Information. Of course, information does have costs associated with its creation, production, and dissemination, or with the building of a system of incentives to generate new or enhanced information. Recovery of costs is certainly legitimate to the extent that such efforts do not bar equitable access to and use of information and data that are essential public goods. Thus, the fundamental heuristic questions are: Does the information or data in question clearly serve the public interest (e.g., biodiversity conservation), and should access to such information be restricted by cost? The issue of appropriate compensations (cost recovery) and incentives (financial or other) for producers of information must be frankly addressed in ways that do not contradict the requirements for free access. (Obviously, when constrained in this way, "cost recovery" is largely limited to other-than-conventional market-based strategies.) A fundamental principle is that, in so far as possible, all biodiversity information from its inception should be dedicated to free not-for-profit, research, education and conservation uses and planning for cost recovery should embrace the fundamental goal of free universal access. (Constraints on this principle may be required in order to extend protections to species or communities subject to targeted exploitation for example, rare orchids, etc.) By careful design and modeling, it is possible to create a technical, legal and policy environment that allows creators/contributors of data or information to permit use to some defined community of conservation stakeholders while maintaining the possibility of cost-recovery (or even for-profit revenues). For example, it is possible that commercial publishers could assign rights to the Commons for selected papers or articles within journals thus conditionally participating labeling the selected articles with the "Biodiversity Commons" logo 6. Attribution and Information IntegrityNon-financial Compensation/Incentives: Integrity and Attribution/Impact. The producers of information have a responsibility to conserve the integrity of their information products, and thus they legitimately expect full respect for the integrity of their information products whether made part of the public domain information or of a commons/conservancy. In the sciences particularly, this expectation of respect for original integrity of information or data is primarily a cultural norm. Disrespect for the integrity of information or data results in the discrediting of resulting work and in shunning of the culpable parties. In addition, creators of information have professional and institutional rights to full attribution/credit for their products. In the current networked digital environment, highly sensitive tools for reporting information use and impact are available; the best possible technologies for measuring and reporting use/impact should be applied to return to responsible creators of information or data, measures of impact of their work. Mechanisms for reporting complex (secondary, tertiary, etc.) uses must also be developed. All such mechanisms must, of course, pay full respect to legitimate concerns for privacy and confidentiality. Implementation ConsiderationsCreation of a Biodiversity Information Commons requires: (a) the establishment of processes and mechanisms for identification, evaluation and selection of relevant data; (b) a thorough understanding of international laws and conventions (e.g., Convention on Biological Diversity7, World Intellectual Property Organization8) and relevant regional and national laws and agreements, including intellectual property rights; and (c) the design and implementation of a fully adequate technical environment for support and sustenance of such a commons. What is to be done?Proposed, as a solution, the creation of a Biodiversity Commons. The international conservation community should:
For the Commons initiative to succeed, broad sectors of the conservation, research and education community will need to participate and provide support. The long-term success of the Biodiversity Commons initiative may determine not whether the South is ever "granted a level playing field" but whether the South is in a very practical way allowed on the field at all. Notes[1] Syed Haider Abbas Zaidi, "Higher Education Pakistan." <http://www2.unesco.org/wef/f_conf/000000e2.htm>. [2] Boyle, James. The second enclosure movement and the construction of the public domain. <http://www.law.duke.edu/pd/papers/boyle.pdf>. [3] See for example: <http://www.scidev.net/dossiers/overview.asp?xc=A005 [4] Reichman, Jerome H. and Paul F. Uhlir, Promoting Public Good Uses of Scientific Data: A Contractually Reconstructed Commons for Science and Innovation. <http://www.law.duke.edu/pd/papers/ReichmanandUhlir.pdf>. [5] Hardin, Garret. The tragedy of the commons. Science, New Series, Vol. 162, Issue 3859 (Dec. 13, 1968) 1243-1248. [6] The logo displays as: biodiversitycommons [7] Convention on Biological Diversity <http://www.biodiv.org/>. [8] World Intellectual Property Organization<http://www.wipo.org/>.
APPENDIX 1
APPENDIX 2
Copyright 2002 Thomas Moritz | |||||||||||||||||
Top | Contents | |||||||||||||||||
D-Lib Magazine Access Terms and Conditions DOI: 10.1045/june2002-moritz
|